Difference between revisions of "National Approaches to Electrification – Technology"

From energypedia
***** (***** | *****)
***** (***** | *****)
m
 
(31 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
  
 
[[File:Back to NAE Overview Page.png|center|800px|NAE Overview Page|alt=NAE Overview Page|link=National Approaches to Electrification – Review of Options]]
 
[[File:Back to NAE Overview Page.png|center|800px|NAE Overview Page|alt=NAE Overview Page|link=National Approaches to Electrification – Review of Options]]
<p style="text-align: center;"><span style="color:#003399;">'''<u>Category Dashboard:</u>'''{{NAE Technology Page Banner}}</span></p>
+
<p style="text-align: center"></p>
<br/>
+
{{Template:NAE Technology Page Banner}}<br/>
  
 
----
 
----
<p style="text-align: center;"><span style="color:#006700ff;">'''Technology:&nbsp;The physical means by which electricity is generated, transmitted and distributed'''</span></p>
+
<p style="text-align: center"><span style="color:#006700ff">'''Technology:&nbsp;The physical means by which electricity is generated, transmitted and distributed'''</span></p>
Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems&nbsp; share characteristics with both Grid Extension and&nbsp;<span style="font-size: 13.6px; background-color: rgb(255, 255, 255);">Isolated Mini-grids – They are linked to the grid system and are able to import electricity from and export electricity to it, so technically they have more in common with Grid Extension. However, in that they are owned and managed independently they are more similar to Isolated Mini-grids. These differences call for different policy and regulatory approaches, so a separate Technology category has been established.</span>
+
[[Portal:Grid|Grid]]-connected [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] and distribution systems&nbsp; share characteristics with both Grid Extension and&nbsp;<span style="font-size: 13.6px; background-color: rgb(255, 255, 255)">Isolated Mini-grids – They are linked to the grid system and are able to import electricity from and export electricity to it, so technically they have more in common with Grid Extension. However, in that they are owned and managed independently they are more similar to Isolated Mini-grids. These differences call for different policy and regulatory approaches, so a separate Technology category has been established.</span>
  
 
----
 
----
Line 14: Line 14:
 
= Grid Extension<br/> =
 
= Grid Extension<br/> =
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF"><span style="font-size: 13.6px">Definition</span></span><br/>
  
| style="width: 618px;" |  
+
| style="width: 618px" |  
 
'''<span>Establishment and extension to new users of a system that connects electricity generation plants to consumers via a transmission and distribution network across the country.</span>'''
 
'''<span>Establishment and extension to new users of a system that connects electricity generation plants to consumers via a transmission and distribution network across the country.</span>'''
  
<span>Grid systems draw on a variety of generation sources, from nuclear and hydro-power to coal, oil and combined-cycle gas turbines and solar- and wind-power. </span><span>Each </span><span>form of generation has different characteristics in terms of flexibility, reliability and costs. A mix of generation sources is required to match generation to demand, with over-reliance on any one form of generation risking lengthy outages (for example, a drought can significantly affect a predominantly hydro-powered grid system). </span><span>Technology advances, combined </span><span>with </span><span>environmental concerns, have led to an increasing focus over recent years on Renewable Energy based generation. </span><span>Transmission and distribution system designs also vary, with low-cost distribution technologies such as Single Wire Earth return (SWER) being used to reduce costs in remote areas.</span><br/>
+
<span>Grid systems draw on a variety of generation sources, from nuclear and hydro-power to coal, oil and combined-cycle gas turbines and [[Portal:Solar|solar]]- and [[Portal:Wind|wind]]-power. </span><span>Each </span><span>form of generation has different characteristics in terms of flexibility, reliability and costs. A mix of generation sources is required to match generation to demand, with over-reliance on any one form of generation risking lengthy outages (for example, a drought can significantly affect a predominantly hydro-powered grid system). </span><span>Technology advances, combined </span><span>with </span><span>environmental concerns, have led to an increasing focus over recent years on Renewable Energy based generation. </span><span>Transmission and distribution system designs also vary, with low-cost distribution technologies such as Single Wire Earth return (SWER) being used to reduce costs in remote areas.</span><br/>
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 28: Line 28:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Internactions wiht other NAE Categories: ==
+
== Interactions with other NAE Categories ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Model</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Delivery Model</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>The national grid system may be publically or privately owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common public-private models for grid systems include:
+
| style="width: 616px" |  
 +
<span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>The national grid system may be publically or privately owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common public-private models for grid systems include:
 +
 
 
*Publically owned generation and transmission, and privately owned distribution;<br/>
 
*Publically owned generation and transmission, and privately owned distribution;<br/>
 
*Independent Power Producers (IPP) connected to a publically owned transmission/distribution system).
 
*Independent Power Producers (IPP) connected to a publically owned transmission/distribution system).
Line 45: Line 47:
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Legual Basis</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF">Legal Basis</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Grid systems almost always act as monopoly concessions (because of the need to balance demand and supply across the system in real-time, and the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). As a result, the right to transmit and sell electricity is often reserved to the national grid utility or company (at least within the area reached by the grid system).
 
Grid systems almost always act as monopoly concessions (because of the need to balance demand and supply across the system in real-time, and the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). As a result, the right to transmit and sell electricity is often reserved to the national grid utility or company (at least within the area reached by the grid system).
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
<span>In line with the nature of the national grid as a single coherent system, uniform </span><span>tariffs </span><span>are almost invariably charged across the system (though often with different tariffs for different classes of user and levels of usage, or in some cases time-of-use pricing). Electricity </span><span>prices </span><span>are a highly political issue in almost every country, and therefore there is almost always some oversight of these tariffs. Without explicit regulation there is a risk of political pressure leading to tariffs which fail to cover costs, and hence system deterioration.&nbsp;&nbsp;</span>
 
<span>In line with the nature of the national grid as a single coherent system, uniform </span><span>tariffs </span><span>are almost invariably charged across the system (though often with different tariffs for different classes of user and levels of usage, or in some cases time-of-use pricing). Electricity </span><span>prices </span><span>are a highly political issue in almost every country, and therefore there is almost always some oversight of these tariffs. Without explicit regulation there is a risk of political pressure leading to tariffs which fail to cover costs, and hence system deterioration.&nbsp;&nbsp;</span>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Finance</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
<span>Almost all national grid systems (including those in developed countries) are constructed using public funding, drawing on government funds sometimes supplemented by concessionary loans and grants from international agencies. Where the grid system is (wholly or partially) privately owned (often as the result of a privatisation process), private investment in infrastructure may be leveraged by subsidies (</span><span>eg</span><span>for connection charges). User charges are the other main source of grid system funding, and uniform tariffs mean that some element of cross-subsidy is inherent in grid-based electricity provision, with users who are more expensive to supply being subsidized by those who can be supplied more cheaply.&nbsp;</span>
 
<span>Almost all national grid systems (including those in developed countries) are constructed using public funding, drawing on government funds sometimes supplemented by concessionary loans and grants from international agencies. Where the grid system is (wholly or partially) privately owned (often as the result of a privatisation process), private investment in infrastructure may be leveraged by subsidies (</span><span>eg</span><span>for connection charges). User charges are the other main source of grid system funding, and uniform tariffs mean that some element of cross-subsidy is inherent in grid-based electricity provision, with users who are more expensive to supply being subsidized by those who can be supplied more cheaply.&nbsp;</span>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><span style="color:#FFFFFF">Non-Financial Interventions</span><span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" |  
+
| style="width: 616px" |  
National energy planning is key to establishing the economically optimum extent of the grid. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target setting may all be beneficial in creating the institutional and policy basis for grid extension. Capacity building or technical assistance may be needed where the key actors involved in grid extension lack capacity. Technology development/adoption and adoption of appropriate technical standards can enable grid extension at lower cost (as shown in the&nbsp;[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|NAE Case Study:Tunisia]]&nbsp;where adoption of standards allowing MALT (Mise A La Terre)&nbsp;distribution lowered costs), while demand promotion may be needed to increase revenues and make it economically&nbsp;sustainable.&nbsp;<br/>
+
National energy planning is key to establishing the economically optimum extent of the grid. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target setting may all be beneficial in creating the institutional and policy basis for grid extension. Capacity building or technical assistance may be needed where the key actors involved in grid extension lack capacity. Technology development/adoption and adoption of appropriate technical standards can enable grid extension at lower cost (as shown in the&nbsp;[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia NAE Case Study]]&nbsp;where adoption of standards allowing MALT (Mise A La Terre)&nbsp;distribution lowered costs), while demand promotion may be needed to increase revenues and make it economically&nbsp;sustainable.&nbsp;<br/>
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 90: Line 92:
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 
Grid extension (combined with construction of additional generation capacity) is particularly appropriate for densely populated areas with higher demand levels, close to the existing grid system. Grid systems provide the ability to build large, efficient generating plants in optimum locations, and make use of economies of scale. These economies may, however, be overwhelmed by the costs of the transmission and distribution infrastructure needed for smaller, more remote communities where mini-grid and off-grid technologies may provide better solutions. Significant extension of the grid also calls for a series of major infrastructure projects, requiring planning, procurement and project management capabilities and is therefore often a lengthy exercise, meaning that other solutions, even if more expensive, may merit consideration as a means to achieve electrification more quickly.&nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp;
 
Grid extension (combined with construction of additional generation capacity) is particularly appropriate for densely populated areas with higher demand levels, close to the existing grid system. Grid systems provide the ability to build large, efficient generating plants in optimum locations, and make use of economies of scale. These economies may, however, be overwhelmed by the costs of the transmission and distribution infrastructure needed for smaller, more remote communities where mini-grid and off-grid technologies may provide better solutions. Significant extension of the grid also calls for a series of major infrastructure projects, requiring planning, procurement and project management capabilities and is therefore often a lengthy exercise, meaning that other solutions, even if more expensive, may merit consideration as a means to achieve electrification more quickly.&nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp; &nbsp;
Line 102: Line 104:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Further Informaiton and Guidance ==
+
== Further Information and Guidance ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 
*Barnes, D. (2007). The Challenge of Rural Electrification: Strategies for Developing Countries. Book Chapter&nbsp;[https://books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0 https://][https://books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0 books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0#v=onepage&q&f=false]
 
*Barnes, D. (2007). The Challenge of Rural Electrification: Strategies for Developing Countries. Book Chapter&nbsp;[https://books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0 https://][https://books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0 books.google.co.uk/books?id=iOBi17Pr3fIC&printsec=frontcover&source=gbs_ge_summary_r&cad=0#v=onepage&q&f=false]
Line 118: Line 120:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Relevante Case Studies: ==
+
== Relevant Case Studies ==
  
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 +
|-
 +
| style="width: 10px;  background-color: rgb(0, 128, 0)" | <br/>
 +
|
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning|Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning|Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|South Africa, Integrated National Electrification]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|South Africa, Integrated National Electrification]]<br/>
*[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]<br/>
+
*[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]
 +
 
 +
|}
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
= Grid-Connected Mini-Grids/Distributed System =
+
{{Go to Top}}
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
<br/>
 +
 
 +
= Grid-Connected Mini-Grid/Distribution System =
 +
 
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(0, 154, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(0, 154, 0)" |  
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/>
+
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF"><span style="font-size: 13.6px">Definition</span></span>'''<br/>
  
| style="width: 618px;" |  
+
| style="width: 618px" |  
 
'''<span><span>An electricity system connected to, but owned and/or separately managed from, the main grid system which supplies electricity to users within a local area.</span></span>'''
 
'''<span><span>An electricity system connected to, but owned and/or separately managed from, the main grid system which supplies electricity to users within a local area.</span></span>'''
  
Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems exist at a wide range of scales from those supplying a few households to systems covering entire districts or regions. The term “grid-connected mini-grid” is most frequently used to refer to systems built around their own, usually small-scale (diesel, bioenergy, biomass, hydro, solar, wind or hybrid) generation and connected to the grid to allow import and export of electricity. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. A “distribution system” generally refers to a larger system designed primarily to distribute electricity from the main grid system to users. However distribution systems often also include their own generation and there is no clear distinction between grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems (and the term “grid-connected mini-grid” is used to refer to both in the description below). At the larger end of the scale, distribution systems may be closely integrated into the main grid system, and the distinction between electrification through grid extension and through grid-connected distribution system expansion is one of ownership and management rather than technology.<br/>Distribution systems generally use lower voltages than for transmission, but the specific boundary between the two varies from country to country. Separate ownership and management may allow grid-connected mini-grids to use lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, but grid system technical requirements (and standards) will generally prevent the lowest capacity “skinny-grids” from becoming grid-connected.<br/>
+
Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems exist at a wide range of scales from those supplying a few households to systems covering entire districts or regions. The term “grid-connected mini-grid” is most frequently used to refer to systems built around their own, usually small-scale (diesel, [[Portal:Bioenergy|bioenergy]], [[Portal:Solid Biomass|biomass]], [[Portal:Hydro|hydro]], [[Portal:Solar|solar]], [[Portal:Wind|windor]] hybrid) generation and connected to the [[Portal:Grid|gridto]] allow import and export of electricity. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. A “distribution system” generally refers to a larger system designed primarily to distribute electricity from the main grid system to users. However distribution systems often also include their own generation and there is no clear distinction between grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems (and the term “grid-connected mini-grid” is used to refer to both in the description below). At the larger end of the scale, distribution systems may be closely integrated into the main grid system, and the distinction between electrification through grid extension and through grid-connected distribution system expansion is one of ownership and management rather than technology.<br/>Distribution systems generally use lower voltages than for transmission, but the specific boundary between the two varies from country to country. Separate ownership and management may allow grid-connected mini-grids to use lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, but grid system technical requirements (and standards) will generally prevent the lowest capacity “skinny-grids” from becoming grid-connected.<br/>
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 142: Line 154:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Internactions wiht other NAE Categories: ==
+
== Interactions with other NAE Categories ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Model</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Delivery Model</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Grid-connected mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:
 
Grid-connected mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:
  
Line 161: Line 173:
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Legual Basis</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Legal Basis</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Larger grid-connected mini-grids will generally require monopoly concessions (because of the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). Even for smaller grid-connected mini-grids, some form of licensing will almost invariably be appropriate to assure investors that they have the right to sell electricity (both to users and the grid), to ensure that technical standards for grid connection are met, and as the means of regulating prices for export and import of electricity from the grid and sale of electricity to users (see price/tariff regulation).&nbsp;<br/>
 
Larger grid-connected mini-grids will generally require monopoly concessions (because of the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). Even for smaller grid-connected mini-grids, some form of licensing will almost invariably be appropriate to assure investors that they have the right to sell electricity (both to users and the grid), to ensure that technical standards for grid connection are met, and as the means of regulating prices for export and import of electricity from the grid and sale of electricity to users (see price/tariff regulation).&nbsp;<br/>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Grid connected mini-grids rely on the sale of electricity to the grid, and import of electricity from the grid and its sale to users, as well as sale of own-generated electricity to users. Clarity on how each of these tariffs is set and regulated will be key to securing investment:
 
Grid connected mini-grids rely on the sale of electricity to the grid, and import of electricity from the grid and its sale to users, as well as sale of own-generated electricity to users. Clarity on how each of these tariffs is set and regulated will be key to securing investment:
  
Line 185: Line 197:
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Finance</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
The primary financing for grid-connected mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from grid-connected mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.<br/>
+
The primary [[Portal:Financing and Funding|financing]]&nbsp;for grid-connected mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from grid-connected mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.<br/>
  
<span style="font-size: 13.6px;">User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between grid-connected mini-grids or between the main grid and grid-connected systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.&nbsp;&nbsp;</span>
+
<span style="font-size: 13.6px">User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between grid-connected mini-grids or between the main grid and grid-connected systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.&nbsp;&nbsp;</span>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" |  
+
| style="width: 616px" |  
 
National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for grid-connected mini-grids. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target-setting may all be required to create the framework for grid-connected mini-grids to be developed and establishment of technical standards is vital for enabling grid-connected mini-grids. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers or those (such as municipalities or user cooperatives) expected to take on responsibility distribution system operation lack capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.&nbsp;
 
National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for grid-connected mini-grids. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target-setting may all be required to create the framework for grid-connected mini-grids to be developed and establishment of technical standards is vital for enabling grid-connected mini-grids. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers or those (such as municipalities or user cooperatives) expected to take on responsibility distribution system operation lack capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.&nbsp;
  
Line 212: Line 224:
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 
Mini-grids are particularly appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels (with off-grid systems providing the best solutions for sparsely populated low-demand areas). For mini-grids to be grid connected they must also be relatively close to the existing grid system. In theory mini-grids should only be the best option where the costs of infrastructure to connect to the grid system out-balance the economies of scale from large-scale centralized generation and pooling demand. Connection to the main grid system allows import and export of electricity and so enables the mini-grid to access these economies of scale and (provided the grid itself is reliable) supports higher levels of quality and reliability – however it also requires construction of connection infrastructure and compliance with grid technical standards. Grid-connected mini-grids can therefore be seen primarily as an alternative to grid extension, with the main differentiator being the ownership and/or management model. If a source of energy for generation exists in an area beyond the extent of the grid, it may provide an opportunity for a mini-grid to be developed to supply local users, and connected to the grid, more quickly than the grid itself would be extended. Management of distribution by the central grid company should provide organisational economies of scale, but in practice separate ownership or management of a local distribution system may increase organisational efficiency and allow an electricity service which is more responsive to users and their needs than that provided by the national grid company.
 
Mini-grids are particularly appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels (with off-grid systems providing the best solutions for sparsely populated low-demand areas). For mini-grids to be grid connected they must also be relatively close to the existing grid system. In theory mini-grids should only be the best option where the costs of infrastructure to connect to the grid system out-balance the economies of scale from large-scale centralized generation and pooling demand. Connection to the main grid system allows import and export of electricity and so enables the mini-grid to access these economies of scale and (provided the grid itself is reliable) supports higher levels of quality and reliability – however it also requires construction of connection infrastructure and compliance with grid technical standards. Grid-connected mini-grids can therefore be seen primarily as an alternative to grid extension, with the main differentiator being the ownership and/or management model. If a source of energy for generation exists in an area beyond the extent of the grid, it may provide an opportunity for a mini-grid to be developed to supply local users, and connected to the grid, more quickly than the grid itself would be extended. Management of distribution by the central grid company should provide organisational economies of scale, but in practice separate ownership or management of a local distribution system may increase organisational efficiency and allow an electricity service which is more responsive to users and their needs than that provided by the national grid company.
Line 224: Line 236:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Further Informaiton and Guidance ==
+
== Further Information and Guidance ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 
*ARE. 2014. Hybrid Mini-Grids for Rural Electrification - Lessons Learned [https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf https://][https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf]
 
*ARE. 2014. Hybrid Mini-Grids for Rural Electrification - Lessons Learned [https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf https://][https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf]
Line 245: Line 257:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Relevante Case Studies: ==
+
== Relevant Case Studies ==
  
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 +
|-
 +
| style="width: 10px;  background-color: rgb(0, 155, 0)" | <br/>
 +
|
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation|Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation|Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation]]<br/>
Line 253: Line 269:
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion|Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion]]<br/>
 
*[[NAE Case Study: Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion|Vietnam, Rapid Grid Expansion]]<br/>
 +
 +
|}
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
= Isolated Mini-Grids =
+
{{Go to Top}}
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
<br/>
 +
 
 +
= Isolated Mini-Grid =
 +
 
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" |  
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/>
+
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF"><span style="font-size: 13.6px">Definition</span></span>'''<br/>
  
| style="width: 618px;" |  
+
| style="width: 618px" |  
 
'''<span><span>A system for generation and distribution of electricity to multiple users which is not connected to the main grid system.</span></span>'''
 
'''<span><span>A system for generation and distribution of electricity to multiple users which is not connected to the main grid system.</span></span>'''
  
Mini-grids exist at a wide range of scales, from those supplying a few households to systems covering several communities. Isolated mini-grids rely on one or more local, usually small-scale (diesel, bioenergy, biomass, hydro, solar, wind or hybrid), generating plants and must balance demand and generation at all times. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. Being separated from the grid system, isolated mini-grids can used lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, and may be designed to provide anything from lighting alone (a “skinny grid”) to a full grid-equivalent electricity service.&nbsp;<br/>
+
Mini-grids exist at a wide range of scales, from those supplying a few households to systems covering several communities. Isolated [[Portal:Mini-grid|mini-grids]] rely on one or more local, usually small-scale (diesel, [[Portal:Bioenergy|bioenergy]], [[Portal:Solid Biomass|biomass]], [[Portal:Hydro|hydro]], [[Portal:Solar|solar]], [[Portal:Wind|windor]] hybrid), generating plants and must balance demand and generation at all times. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. Being separated from the grid system, isolated mini-grids can used lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, and may be designed to provide anything from lighting alone (a “skinny grid”) to a full grid-equivalent electricity service.&nbsp;<br/>
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 272: Line 294:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Internactions wiht other NAE Categories: ==
+
== Interactions with other NAE Categories ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Model</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Delivery Model</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Isolated mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:
 
Isolated mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:
  
Line 291: Line 313:
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Legual Basis</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Legal Basis</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
Mini-grids require substantial, long-term, capital investment and hence a regulatory framework which will give developers, and particularly private financiers, confidence that there will be a market for electricity from the mini-grid for a long enough period to repay and provide an adequate return on their investment. Larger systems may require concessions (which protect against competition over a designated area and time period) to give investors the confidence in revenue forecasts to commit the long-term capital investment needed. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (which grants a non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. Mini-grids below a certain size (eg <100kW in Tanzania), are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from regulation.&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;
+
Mini-grids require substantial, long-term, capital investment and hence a regulatory framework which will give developers, and particularly private financiers, confidence that there will be a market for electricity from the mini-grid for a long enough period to repay and provide an adequate return on their investment. Larger systems may require concessions (which protect against competition over a designated area and time period) to give investors the confidence in revenue forecasts to commit the long-term capital investment needed. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (which grants a non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. Mini-grids below a certain size (eg <100kW in the [[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania NAE Case Study]]), are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from regulation.&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;
  
 
Under any regulatory regime a key question for private mini-grid investors will be what happens when the main grid arrives? Grid extension into a mini-grid concession area within the concession period may be prohibited by the terms of the concession, or there may be explicit provision for compensation and transfer of assets to grid ownership. mini-grid licensees have less protection from grid extension than concessionaires, but even where there is no formal concession it is often beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim.
 
Under any regulatory regime a key question for private mini-grid investors will be what happens when the main grid arrives? Grid extension into a mini-grid concession area within the concession period may be prohibited by the terms of the concession, or there may be explicit provision for compensation and transfer of assets to grid ownership. mini-grid licensees have less protection from grid extension than concessionaires, but even where there is no formal concession it is often beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim.
  
Where mini-grids are delivered through a public model with purely public finance, the legal basis will generally be less critical as public financiers are less likely to be concerned about recovery of and return on investment through future revenues.
+
Where mini-grids are delivered through a public model with purely public [[Portal:Financing and Funding|finance]], the legal basis will generally be less critical as public financiers are less likely to be concerned about recovery of and return on investment through future revenues.
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
 
Isolated mini-grids rely on revenues from the sale of electricity to users to cover ongoing operating,&nbsp; maintenance and administrative costs and repayment and return on investment. Regulation of tariff levels is therefore&nbsp; a critical factor for private investors in mini-grids, with inadequate or inappropriate tariff regulation often cited as the key barrier to mini-grid investment.<br/>
 
Isolated mini-grids rely on revenues from the sale of electricity to users to cover ongoing operating,&nbsp; maintenance and administrative costs and repayment and return on investment. Regulation of tariff levels is therefore&nbsp; a critical factor for private investors in mini-grids, with inadequate or inappropriate tariff regulation often cited as the key barrier to mini-grid investment.<br/>
  
Line 319: Line 341:
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Finance</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
Financing for isolated mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.
+
[[Portal:Financing and Funding|Financing]]&nbsp;for isolated mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.
  
 
User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users, there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between isolated mini-grids or between the main grid and mini-grid systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.
 
User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users, there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between isolated mini-grids or between the main grid and mini-grid systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" |  
+
| style="width: 616px" |  
 
National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned<br/>extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for isolated mini-grids. Regulatory reform and policy and target-setting are likely to be required to create the framework for isolated mini-grids to be developed. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers lack necessary skills and capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.<br/>
 
National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned<br/>extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for isolated mini-grids. Regulatory reform and policy and target-setting are likely to be required to create the framework for isolated mini-grids to be developed. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers lack necessary skills and capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.<br/>
  
Line 343: Line 365:
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
 
  
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 
Mini-grids are most appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels which are distant from the grid system, particularly where there is a good local source of energy for electricity generation. Because mini-grids rely on local, small-scale, generation, and their demand profiles often have pronounced peaks (because their users want electricity at the same times of day), their generating costs are usually higher than costs of electricity from larger power plants connected to the main grid, so in areas closer to the grid, where the cost of connecting to the grid is relatively low, grid extension will usually be more economic. In sparsely populated low-demand areas, standalone systems, despite their higher generating costs, may be more economic because they avoid the cost of a distribution system. mini-grids may also, even in areas for which grid extension would be more economic in the longer term, provide a means for achieving energy access more quickly.
 
Mini-grids are most appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels which are distant from the grid system, particularly where there is a good local source of energy for electricity generation. Because mini-grids rely on local, small-scale, generation, and their demand profiles often have pronounced peaks (because their users want electricity at the same times of day), their generating costs are usually higher than costs of electricity from larger power plants connected to the main grid, so in areas closer to the grid, where the cost of connecting to the grid is relatively low, grid extension will usually be more economic. In sparsely populated low-demand areas, standalone systems, despite their higher generating costs, may be more economic because they avoid the cost of a distribution system. mini-grids may also, even in areas for which grid extension would be more economic in the longer term, provide a means for achieving energy access more quickly.
Line 359: Line 380:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
 +
== Further Information and Guidance ==
 +
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 +
|-
 +
| style="width: 10px;  background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <br/>
 +
|
 +
*ARE. 2014. Hybrid Mini-Grids for Rural Electrification - Lessons Learned [https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf https://][https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf]
 +
*<div>ESMAP (2005), Meeting the Challenge of Rural Electrification in Developing Nations: The Experience of Successful Programs [https://static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT https://][https://static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT static.globalinnovationexchange.org/s3fs-public/asset/document/Meeting0the0Ch10Discussion0Version0.pdf?q3Tol9Bdn4yH4J43t3P9t3hq5lh6ZipT]</div>
 +
*<div><span>EUEI </span><span>PDF (2014), Mini-grid Policy Toolkit: Policy and Business Frameworks for Successful Mini-grid Roll-outs&nbsp;[http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_MiniGrid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_MiniGrid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf]&nbsp;&nbsp;</span><br/></div>
 +
*<div><span></span>IRENA (2016), Innovation Outlook: Renewable Mini-grids, International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi [http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf http://][http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Innovation_Outlook_Minigrids_2016.pdf]</div>
 +
*IRENA (2016), Policies and regulations to support renewable energy mini-grid [http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf http://][http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf]<br/>
 +
*World Bank. 2014. From the Bottom Up. How Small Power Producers and Mini-Grids Can Deliver Electrification and Renewable Energy in Africa. [https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571 https://][https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571 openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/16571]
 +
 +
|}
  
 +
<br/>
  
== Further Informaiton and Guidance ==
+
== Relevant Case Studies ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(103, 153, 0)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
*ARE. 2014. Hybrid Mini-Grids for Rural Electrification - Lessons Learned [https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf https://][https://ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf ruralelec.org/sites/default/files/hybrid_mini-grids_for_rural_electrification_2014.pdf]
+
*[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation|Cambodia “Light Touch” Regulation]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Kenya, Off-Grid for Vision 2030|Kenya, Off-Grid for Vision 2030]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Mali, Rural Electrification Programme|Mali, Rural Electrification Programme]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Nepal, Rural Energy Development Programme|Nepal, Rural Energy Development Programme]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives|Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning|Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework|Tanzania, Mini-Grids Regulatory Framework]]
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 373: Line 416:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
 
+
{{Go to Top}}
== Relevante Case Studies: ==
 
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
Line 380: Line 422:
 
= Standalone Systems =
 
= Standalone Systems =
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" |  
+
| style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" |  
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/>
+
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF"><span style="font-size: 13.6px">Definition</span></span>'''<br/>
  
| style="width: 618px;" |  
+
| style="width: 618px" |  
<span><span>A system for generating and supplying electricity to a single user (separate from any distribution system).</span></span>
+
'''<span><span>A system for generating and supplying electricity to a single user (separate from any distribution system).</span></span>'''<br/>
 +
 
 +
'''<span><span></span></span>'''Standalone systems may use any locally available source of energy (including [[Portal:Solar|solar]], [[Portal:Wind|wind]], [[Portal:Hydro|hydropower]], [[Portal:Biogas|biogas]], [[Portal:Solid Biomass|biomass]], [[Portal:Biofuel|biofuelsor]] diesel generators). While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. They may serve a single purpose (such as lighting or irrigation water-pumping) or be designed to meet all the electricity needs of the user. They range in size from solar lanterns, through small household systems to larger installations serving industrial enterprises (though for the purposes of this review the focus is on systems suitable for households, community facilities and SMEs).<br/>
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 392: Line 436:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Internactions wiht other NAE Categories: ==
+
== Interactions with other NAE Categories ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(51, 103, 152)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Model</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Delivery Model</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
<br/>
+
Standalone systems are most frequently supplied to users through a purely private-sector chain of manufacturers, importers, distributors and retailers. In a number of cases (such as shown in the [[NAE Case Study: Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems|NAE Case Study of the IDCOL programme in Bangladesh]]), public-private partnership models have been used. In general this has been through use of public [[Portal:Financing and Funding|finance]]&nbsp;(grants, subsidies and loans) to enhance affordability and support market growth, though there could be benefits in certain circumstances for government energy agencies to become directly involved in the standalone system market, by forming a joint entity to supply systems or by taking on one of the roles along the value chain (eg providing a distribution service for all system providers). More rarely a purely public model is used to provide standalone systems to users, for example where the grid company provides standalone systems to those it is not economic to connect to the grid (eg in [[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|NAE Case Study South Africa]]).&nbsp;<br/>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(154, 103, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Legual Basis</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Legal Basis</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
<br/>
+
Standalone system providers are rarely subject to regulation (beyond general business licensing requirements), though they may be required to meet certain standards in order to access subsidies and tax exemptions. In part this reflects&nbsp; policy-makers’ perception of them as product retailers rather than infrastructure providers, but also that without long-term fixed capital investment, private companies have not needed the protection of a concession or license to attract private capital (and would regard it simply as a regulatory burden). Concessions for standalone systems may however, as in [[NAE Case Study: Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems|NAE Case Study Peru]], be used to bring standalone system companies into a market which they might otherwise be unwilling to enter by protecting them from competition (though the long-term risks of market distortion under such an arrangement should be carefully considered). Standalone systems may also be included as one means of providing electricity within an integrated electricity concession also encompassing mini-grid and/or grid system access. It’s also possible that with standalone system providers increasingly looking to pay-as-you-go arrangements, where they retain ownership of the system until the user has bought it through monthly payments, or even over its full life with the user simply paying for electricity used, regulating electricity supply through standalone systems may become more appropriate.
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
<br/>
+
Prices of standalone systems supplied by the private sector are generally unregulated. Where public funding is used to support provision of standalone systems it may (as with the [[NAE Case Study: Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems|NAE Case Study of the IDCOL programme in Bangladesh]]) be appropriate to regulate prices. Also, if the move towards pay-as-you-go, with users paying for electricity as they do from grid or mini-grids, while suppliers retain ownership of the capital equipment, continues or accelerates, regulation of the prices they pay may become more relevant. Regulation of prices for standalone systems, or of electricity supplied through these systems, on an individual basis is impractical given the multiplicity of systems. Uniform price regulation, where a standard price or tariff is set is more likely to be viable. However, any such regulation should recognize the differentials in costs between different types and sizes of standalone system, and parity with grid (or mini-grid) prices should only be attempted if subsidies are available to balance the cost differentials between these different Technologies.<br/>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Finance</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span>
+
| style="width: 616px" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span>
<br/>
+
Though provision of standalone systems requires less capital investment than investment in grid or mini-grid systems, those establishing standalone system business nevertheless require capital for business development and working capital to fund the period (typically three months or more) between purchase/ import of the product by the business and sale to the end-user. Because standalone systems are often imported, this also brings a requirement for access to foreign capital. Where standalone systems are sold to users, it is to these users that much of the requirement for capital investment falls. This need for up-front user [[Portal:Financing and Funding|finance]]&nbsp;has formed one of the most substantial barriers to growth of markets for standalone systems (even where these systems are demonstrably an economic option for the user in the longer term). This barrier can be alleviated through micro-finance and similar programmes, and has also driven the growth of pay-as-you-go arrangements whereby the need for up-front finance is transferred to the supplier (though users remain the ultimate source of finance through their payments for electricity).&nbsp; Though most standalone system providers are private companies, many have struggled to access private finance, reflecting private financiers reluctance to invest in start-up companies without established track-records seeking to grow a new market. Instead many have relied on finance from donors and social funders. This has been one of the main constraints on standalone system market growth.&nbsp; Public finance, through grants, subsidies and concessionary loans (to both suppliers and users) and tax exemptions (eg VAT and import duty exemptions) have been used to make standalone systems more affordable to users.&nbsp;<br/>
  
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF"></span><br/>
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" |  
+
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100)" |  
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
+
<span style="color:#FFFFFF">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/>
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
| style="width: 616px;" |  
+
| style="width: 616px" |  
<br/>
+
Clear national policies and targets and availability of market information have been identified as key factors enabling standalone system providers to assess market scale and so encourage market entry. Regulatory reform, particularly in the [[Portal:Financing and Funding|finance]]&nbsp;sector to enable pay-as-you-go arrangements is also seen as vital, as is establishment and enforcement of quality standards to give consumers confidence in products. Exemption from taxes and duties (particularly where this is needed to create a level playing field with other forms of energy access) can catalyse market development, and user awareness raising and development of a workforce with the technical and business skills need to support business growth are also important (and beyond the capacity of individual standalone system businesses) to support its growth.
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 451: Line 495:
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
 
== Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided) ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 +
Standalone systems encompass a wide range of technologies from solar lanterns, to [[Solar Home Systems (SHS)|solar home systems]] and [[Solar-Powered Pumps for Improved Irrigation|pumps]], to larger scale diesel, hydro, biomass and wind-powered generators. Because they lack the economies of scale provided by grid (or even mini-grid) systems, the cost per unit of electricity from standalone systems is generally higher than from a grid (or mini-grid) connection. However in areas which are remote from the grid system and are sparsely populated (or lack a substantial energy source), standalone systems may provide the lowest cost option for electricity supply because they avoid the cost of distribution infrastructure. In addition, while the cost per unit of electricity may be relatively high, for low-demand users (eg those only looking for lighting and phone charging) they can still offer the most economic solution. Standalone solutions are also used by those who want back-up for an unreliable grid or mini-grid supply, or who want independence from the grid system.&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;&nbsp;
 +
 +
In line with the wide range of technologies encompassed by standalone systems, they can be designed to provide any level of electricity. In general, however, the differential in cost between grid/mini-grid and standalone systems increases as the level of supply goes up (particularly for [[Basic Energy Services - Stand Alone / Off grid Energy Systems|solar standalone systems]]), and standalone household systems therefore most often provide only Tier 1 (or even lower) access and rarely provide more than Tier 2-3 access, though systems for enterprises and community facilities may be larger and provide a higher level of access (with larger systems often being supported by hydro or fuel rather than solar generation).&nbsp;&nbsp;
 +
 +
|}
 +
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
 +
 +
== Further Information and Guidance ==
 +
 +
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 +
|-
 +
| style="width: 10px;  background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <br/>
 +
|
 +
*Practical Action, ODI, Solar Aid, GOGLA. (2016). Accelerating Access to Electricity in Africa with Off-grid Solar [https://policy.practicalaction.org/policy-themes/energy/off-grid-solar https://][https://policy.practicalaction.org/policy-themes/energy/off-grid-solar policy.practicalaction.org/policy-themes/energy/off-grid-solar]
 +
*UNEP & GOGLA, (2015), Developing Effective Off-Grid Lighting Policy. [https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf https://][https://www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf www.gogla.org/sites/www.gogla.org/files/recource_docs/developing-effective-off-grid-lighting-policy.pdf]
  
 
|}
 
|}
Line 461: Line 520:
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Further Informaiton and Guidance ==
+
== Relevant Case Studies ==
  
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;"
+
{| style="width:100%" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" border="1"
 
|-
 
|-
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141);" | <br/>
+
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(171, 211, 141)" | <br/>
 
|  
 
|  
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems|Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Ethiopia, Solar Market Development|Ethiopia, Solar Market Development]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Kenya, Off-Grid for Vision 2030|Kenya, Off-Grid for Vision 2030]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems|Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning|Rwanda, Sector-Wide Approach to Planning]]<br/>
 +
*[[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|South Africa, Integrated National Electrification]]<br/>
 +
 
|}
 
|}
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
== Relevante Case Studies: ==
+
{{Go to Top}}
  
 
<br/>
 
<br/>
  
----
+
= References =
  
[[File:Back to NAE Overview Page.png|center|800px|NAE Overview Page|alt=NAE Overview Page|link=National Approaches to Electrification – Review of Options]]
+
{{NAE Acknowledgements}}
  
 +
[[Category:Rural_Electrification]]
 +
[[Category:Energy_Access]]
 +
[[Category:Grid_Integration]]
 +
[[Category:Grid]]
 +
[[Category:Mini-grid]]
 
[[Category:NAE]]
 
[[Category:NAE]]

Latest revision as of 14:09, 30 July 2018

NAE Overview Page

TechnologyTechnology: Grid ExtensionTechnology: Grid-Connected Mini-Grid/Distribution SystemTechnology: Isolated Mini-GridTechnology: Standalone SystemsDelivery ModelDelivery Model: PublicDelivery Model: Private (Non-Government)Delivery Model: Public-Private PartnershipLegal BasisLegal Basis: ConcessionLegal Basis: LicenseLegal Basis / Price/Tariff Regulation: UnregulatedPrice/Tariff RegulationPrice/Tariff Regulation: UniformPrice/Tariff Regulation: IndividualFinanceFinance: PrivateFinance : UserFinance: Grants & SubsidiesFinance: Cross-SubsidiesFinance: Tax ExemptionsFinance: GuaranteesNon-Financial InterventionsNon-Financial Interventions: Direct Energy Access ProvisionNon-Financial Interventions: Institutional RestructuringNon-Financial Interventions: Regulatory ReformNon-Financial Interventions: Policy & Target SettingNon-Financial Interventions: Quality & Technical StandardsNon-Financial Interventions: Technical AssistanceNon-Financial Interventions: Capacity Building & Awareness RaisingNon-Financial Interventions: Market InformationNon-Financial Interventions: Demand PromotionNon-Financial Interventions: Technology Development & AdoptionNon-Financial Interventions: National Energy PlanningNational Approaches to Electrification – Technology Page.png]]



Technology: The physical means by which electricity is generated, transmitted and distributed

Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems  share characteristics with both Grid Extension and Isolated Mini-grids – They are linked to the grid system and are able to import electricity from and export electricity to it, so technically they have more in common with Grid Extension. However, in that they are owned and managed independently they are more similar to Isolated Mini-grids. These differences call for different policy and regulatory approaches, so a separate Technology category has been established.



Grid Extension

Definition

Establishment and extension to new users of a system that connects electricity generation plants to consumers via a transmission and distribution network across the country.

Grid systems draw on a variety of generation sources, from nuclear and hydro-power to coal, oil and combined-cycle gas turbines and solar- and wind-power. Each form of generation has different characteristics in terms of flexibility, reliability and costs. A mix of generation sources is required to match generation to demand, with over-reliance on any one form of generation risking lengthy outages (for example, a drought can significantly affect a predominantly hydro-powered grid system). Technology advances, combined with environmental concerns, have led to an increasing focus over recent years on Renewable Energy based generation. Transmission and distribution system designs also vary, with low-cost distribution technologies such as Single Wire Earth return (SWER) being used to reduce costs in remote areas.


Interactions with other NAE Categories


Delivery Model


The national grid system may be publically or privately owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common public-private models for grid systems include:

  • Publically owned generation and transmission, and privately owned distribution;
  • Independent Power Producers (IPP) connected to a publically owned transmission/distribution system).

(Where individual distribution areas are separately owned, eg by municipalities or regional bodies, these may be regarded as grid-connected distribution systems and are discussed under that category). 


Legal Basis


Grid systems almost always act as monopoly concessions (because of the need to balance demand and supply across the system in real-time, and the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). As a result, the right to transmit and sell electricity is often reserved to the national grid utility or company (at least within the area reached by the grid system).


Price/Tariff Regulation


In line with the nature of the national grid as a single coherent system, uniform tariffs are almost invariably charged across the system (though often with different tariffs for different classes of user and levels of usage, or in some cases time-of-use pricing). Electricity prices are a highly political issue in almost every country, and therefore there is almost always some oversight of these tariffs. Without explicit regulation there is a risk of political pressure leading to tariffs which fail to cover costs, and hence system deterioration.  


Finance


Almost all national grid systems (including those in developed countries) are constructed using public funding, drawing on government funds sometimes supplemented by concessionary loans and grants from international agencies. Where the grid system is (wholly or partially) privately owned (often as the result of a privatisation process), private investment in infrastructure may be leveraged by subsidies (egfor connection charges). User charges are the other main source of grid system funding, and uniform tariffs mean that some element of cross-subsidy is inherent in grid-based electricity provision, with users who are more expensive to supply being subsidized by those who can be supplied more cheaply. 


Non-Financial Interventions


National energy planning is key to establishing the economically optimum extent of the grid. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target setting may all be beneficial in creating the institutional and policy basis for grid extension. Capacity building or technical assistance may be needed where the key actors involved in grid extension lack capacity. Technology development/adoption and adoption of appropriate technical standards can enable grid extension at lower cost (as shown in the Tunisia NAE Case Study where adoption of standards allowing MALT (Mise A La Terre) distribution lowered costs), while demand promotion may be needed to increase revenues and make it economically sustainable. 


Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided)


Grid extension (combined with construction of additional generation capacity) is particularly appropriate for densely populated areas with higher demand levels, close to the existing grid system. Grid systems provide the ability to build large, efficient generating plants in optimum locations, and make use of economies of scale. These economies may, however, be overwhelmed by the costs of the transmission and distribution infrastructure needed for smaller, more remote communities where mini-grid and off-grid technologies may provide better solutions. Significant extension of the grid also calls for a series of major infrastructure projects, requiring planning, procurement and project management capabilities and is therefore often a lengthy exercise, meaning that other solutions, even if more expensive, may merit consideration as a means to achieve electrification more quickly.         

Grid systems are usually designed to provide a high level of electricity, suitable to serve all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 51). However, where generation is inadequate (or liable to interruption); or transmission and distribution systems are insufficiently robust or poorly maintained; reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate. Thus while users have a physical connection to the grid, they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity (bringing the supply Tier 3 or lower). It is therefore important to couple grid extension with  development of additional generation capacity to support the resulting additional demand.


Further Information and Guidance



Relevant Case Studies



►Go to Top


Grid-Connected Mini-Grid/Distribution System

Definition

An electricity system connected to, but owned and/or separately managed from, the main grid system which supplies electricity to users within a local area.

Grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems exist at a wide range of scales from those supplying a few households to systems covering entire districts or regions. The term “grid-connected mini-grid” is most frequently used to refer to systems built around their own, usually small-scale (diesel, bioenergy, biomass, hydro, solar, windor hybrid) generation and connected to the gridto allow import and export of electricity. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. A “distribution system” generally refers to a larger system designed primarily to distribute electricity from the main grid system to users. However distribution systems often also include their own generation and there is no clear distinction between grid-connected mini-grids and distribution systems (and the term “grid-connected mini-grid” is used to refer to both in the description below). At the larger end of the scale, distribution systems may be closely integrated into the main grid system, and the distinction between electrification through grid extension and through grid-connected distribution system expansion is one of ownership and management rather than technology.
Distribution systems generally use lower voltages than for transmission, but the specific boundary between the two varies from country to country. Separate ownership and management may allow grid-connected mini-grids to use lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, but grid system technical requirements (and standards) will generally prevent the lowest capacity “skinny-grids” from becoming grid-connected.


Interactions with other NAE Categories


Delivery Model


Grid-connected mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:

  • mini-grids owned by a private developer connected to the main grid;
  • A private enterprise installing generation to meet its own power demand building a local distribution system and supply to other local users and the grid;    
  • A municipality or other local public entity operating a grid connected distribution system;
  • A private company, or public-private partnership taking on operation of a section of the grid distribution system as part of a privatisation process.

Legal Basis


Larger grid-connected mini-grids will generally require monopoly concessions (because of the substantial investment required to establish and maintain the infrastructure). Even for smaller grid-connected mini-grids, some form of licensing will almost invariably be appropriate to assure investors that they have the right to sell electricity (both to users and the grid), to ensure that technical standards for grid connection are met, and as the means of regulating prices for export and import of electricity from the grid and sale of electricity to users (see price/tariff regulation). 


Price/Tariff Regulation


Grid connected mini-grids rely on the sale of electricity to the grid, and import of electricity from the grid and its sale to users, as well as sale of own-generated electricity to users. Clarity on how each of these tariffs is set and regulated will be key to securing investment:

  • Setting a standard price for purchase of electricity from the grid, or defining what category of user grid-connected mini-grids fall under, and having a transparent process for adjusting these prices (rather than leaving them to be negotiated between individual developers and the grid company) will give investors confidence;
  • A standard price for sale of electricity to the grid (a feed-in tariff), based for instance on the grid company’s avoided cost (as in Tanzania) or an expected average cost from a particular form of generation, will similarly reduce mini-grid development costs and risks;
  • Regulation of user tariffs for grid-connected mini-grids will be particularly sensitive given that the mini-grid operator may be drawing on the grid system to supply its users. Applying a uniform tariff (particularly a grid-parity) tariff is likely to offer some grid-connected mini-grids super-profits while making others uneconomic, but an approach based on a margin above the price for purchasing electricity from the grid may be appropriate (particularly where the system acts primarily as a means for distributing electricity from the grid and has little own-generation capacity). In general a cost-recovery approach, taking account of system-specific costs and any subsidies is likely to work best, and clarity and transparency of the process will be key for investors.

Finance


The primary financing for grid-connected mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from grid-connected mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.

User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between grid-connected mini-grids or between the main grid and grid-connected systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.  


Non-Financial Interventions


National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for grid-connected mini-grids. Institutional restructuring, regulatory reform and policy and target-setting may all be required to create the framework for grid-connected mini-grids to be developed and establishment of technical standards is vital for enabling grid-connected mini-grids. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers or those (such as municipalities or user cooperatives) expected to take on responsibility distribution system operation lack capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable. 


Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided)


Mini-grids are particularly appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels (with off-grid systems providing the best solutions for sparsely populated low-demand areas). For mini-grids to be grid connected they must also be relatively close to the existing grid system. In theory mini-grids should only be the best option where the costs of infrastructure to connect to the grid system out-balance the economies of scale from large-scale centralized generation and pooling demand. Connection to the main grid system allows import and export of electricity and so enables the mini-grid to access these economies of scale and (provided the grid itself is reliable) supports higher levels of quality and reliability – however it also requires construction of connection infrastructure and compliance with grid technical standards. Grid-connected mini-grids can therefore be seen primarily as an alternative to grid extension, with the main differentiator being the ownership and/or management model. If a source of energy for generation exists in an area beyond the extent of the grid, it may provide an opportunity for a mini-grid to be developed to supply local users, and connected to the grid, more quickly than the grid itself would be extended. Management of distribution by the central grid company should provide organisational economies of scale, but in practice separate ownership or management of a local distribution system may increase organisational efficiency and allow an electricity service which is more responsive to users and their needs than that provided by the national grid company.

Grid-connected mini-grids can, in theory, provide any level of electricity supply, but in most cases if the investment is made for grid connection and associated standards are met, they  provide a grid-equivalent service, meeting all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 5). (If the grid system itself is over-stretched with inadequate generation; or insufficiently robust or poorly maintained transmission and distribution systems reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate so that while users have a physical connection, they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity (bringing the supply Tier 3 or lower). To the extent that a grid-connected mini-grid draws on electricity from the grid its construction should be coupled with development of additional centralized generation capacity to support the resulting additional demand.


Further Information and Guidance



Relevant Case Studies



►Go to Top


Isolated Mini-Grid

Definition

A system for generation and distribution of electricity to multiple users which is not connected to the main grid system.

Mini-grids exist at a wide range of scales, from those supplying a few households to systems covering several communities. Isolated mini-grids rely on one or more local, usually small-scale (diesel, bioenergy, biomass, hydro, solar, windor hybrid), generating plants and must balance demand and generation at all times. While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. Being separated from the grid system, isolated mini-grids can used lower voltages and lower-cost technologies than the main grid, and may be designed to provide anything from lighting alone (a “skinny grid”) to a full grid-equivalent electricity service. 


Interactions with other NAE Categories


Delivery Model


Isolated mini-grids are often privately owned, but may be publically owned or combine both in a public-private partnership. Common models include:

  • An isolated mini-grid owned by a private developer, a user-cooperative or community organisation;
  • Mini-grids owned and operated by the national grid company in off-grid areas;
  • A mini-grid operated by a municipality or other local public entity to supply an off-grid community;
  • Isolated mini-grids developed under a Public-Private Partnership, for instance on a Build-Own-Operate-Transfer basis.

Legal Basis


Mini-grids require substantial, long-term, capital investment and hence a regulatory framework which will give developers, and particularly private financiers, confidence that there will be a market for electricity from the mini-grid for a long enough period to repay and provide an adequate return on their investment. Larger systems may require concessions (which protect against competition over a designated area and time period) to give investors the confidence in revenue forecasts to commit the long-term capital investment needed. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (which grants a non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. Mini-grids below a certain size (eg <100kW in the Tanzania NAE Case Study), are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from regulation.     

Under any regulatory regime a key question for private mini-grid investors will be what happens when the main grid arrives? Grid extension into a mini-grid concession area within the concession period may be prohibited by the terms of the concession, or there may be explicit provision for compensation and transfer of assets to grid ownership. mini-grid licensees have less protection from grid extension than concessionaires, but even where there is no formal concession it is often beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim.

Where mini-grids are delivered through a public model with purely public finance, the legal basis will generally be less critical as public financiers are less likely to be concerned about recovery of and return on investment through future revenues.


Price/Tariff Regulation


Isolated mini-grids rely on revenues from the sale of electricity to users to cover ongoing operating,  maintenance and administrative costs and repayment and return on investment. Regulation of tariff levels is therefore  a critical factor for private investors in mini-grids, with inadequate or inappropriate tariff regulation often cited as the key barrier to mini-grid investment.

A uniform-tariff regime, where all mini-grid operators must charge the same tariffs, has the attraction of apparent equity, but will generally encourage investment only in those areas where electricity can be supplied at a lower cost allowing the investor to retain a margin and discourage investment in harder to supply areas (unless public funding/subsidy, or cross-subsidies, are made available to overcome higher costs). Individually set tariffs, based on costs specific to individual mini-grid contexts, are more likely to encourage investments in more remote areas.

Whatever form of tariff regulation is used the critical requirement is that it is clear and transparent, to reduce project development costs and give private financiers confidence that revenues from mini-grids are not vulnerable to arbitrary regulatory decisions and political pressure.


Finance


Financing for isolated mini-grids will generally align with the delivery model, with publically-owned mini-grids using public finance and privately owned mini-grids drawing on private finance. However, where incomes are lower or system costs higher, some form of public-private partnership is likely to be needed with public funding (eg through grants and subsidies) making electricity from mini-grids affordable to users and the mini-grid systems economically sustainable.

User charges are the other main source of funding with connection charges and ongoing tariffs are used to contribute to investment, cover ongoing operating costs and support repayment and return on investment. As with any system supplying multiple users, there is likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users connected to any individual mini-grid system. Cross-subsidy between isolated mini-grids or between the main grid and mini-grid systems may be appropriate, particularly if a uniform tariff is applied.


Non-Financial Interventions


National energy planning and sharing of market information are key to establishing the planned
extent and timescales for grid extension and hence the scope for isolated mini-grids. Regulatory reform and policy and target-setting are likely to be required to create the framework for isolated mini-grids to be developed. Capacity building or technical assistance may be beneficial where potential developers lack necessary skills and capabilities. User awareness raising and demand promotion are often essential to increase revenues and make mini-grids economically sustainable.


Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided)


Mini-grids are most appropriate for relatively densely populated areas with higher demand levels which are distant from the grid system, particularly where there is a good local source of energy for electricity generation. Because mini-grids rely on local, small-scale, generation, and their demand profiles often have pronounced peaks (because their users want electricity at the same times of day), their generating costs are usually higher than costs of electricity from larger power plants connected to the main grid, so in areas closer to the grid, where the cost of connecting to the grid is relatively low, grid extension will usually be more economic. In sparsely populated low-demand areas, standalone systems, despite their higher generating costs, may be more economic because they avoid the cost of a distribution system. mini-grids may also, even in areas for which grid extension would be more economic in the longer term, provide a means for achieving energy access more quickly.

Mini-grids may be designed to provide any level of electricity access, from “skinny-grid”, which just support lighting and, perhaps phone-charging (Tier 1) to a grid-equivalent service, meeting all household, commercial, industrial and community requirements (Tier 5). In many more remote communities where isolated mini-grids are the most appropriate solution, it is a Tier 2-3 level (to support medium power appliances such as fans, refrigerators, small water pumps and hand tools). In theory, the grid system which is able to call on multiple sources of generation should be more reliable than an isolated mini-grid, but in practice if the grid system itself is over-stretched with inadequate generation; or insufficiently robust or poorly maintained transmission and distribution systems, reliability and quality of supply may deteriorate so that while users have a physical connection they may not in fact have reliable access to electricity. Poor grid reliability is one of the reasons many users turn to mini-grids and standalone systems even in areas where grid connection is available.


Further Information and Guidance



Relevant Case Studies



►Go to Top


Standalone Systems

Definition

A system for generating and supplying electricity to a single user (separate from any distribution system).

Standalone systems may use any locally available source of energy (including solar, wind, hydropower, biogas, biomass, biofuelsor diesel generators). While these include fossil-fuel based generation, technology advances combined with environmental concerns mean that policy-makers are increasingly focussing on encouraging Renewable Energy based generation. They may serve a single purpose (such as lighting or irrigation water-pumping) or be designed to meet all the electricity needs of the user. They range in size from solar lanterns, through small household systems to larger installations serving industrial enterprises (though for the purposes of this review the focus is on systems suitable for households, community facilities and SMEs).


Interactions with other NAE Categories


Delivery Model


Standalone systems are most frequently supplied to users through a purely private-sector chain of manufacturers, importers, distributors and retailers. In a number of cases (such as shown in the NAE Case Study of the IDCOL programme in Bangladesh), public-private partnership models have been used. In general this has been through use of public finance (grants, subsidies and loans) to enhance affordability and support market growth, though there could be benefits in certain circumstances for government energy agencies to become directly involved in the standalone system market, by forming a joint entity to supply systems or by taking on one of the roles along the value chain (eg providing a distribution service for all system providers). More rarely a purely public model is used to provide standalone systems to users, for example where the grid company provides standalone systems to those it is not economic to connect to the grid (eg in NAE Case Study South Africa). 


Legal Basis


Standalone system providers are rarely subject to regulation (beyond general business licensing requirements), though they may be required to meet certain standards in order to access subsidies and tax exemptions. In part this reflects  policy-makers’ perception of them as product retailers rather than infrastructure providers, but also that without long-term fixed capital investment, private companies have not needed the protection of a concession or license to attract private capital (and would regard it simply as a regulatory burden). Concessions for standalone systems may however, as in NAE Case Study Peru, be used to bring standalone system companies into a market which they might otherwise be unwilling to enter by protecting them from competition (though the long-term risks of market distortion under such an arrangement should be carefully considered). Standalone systems may also be included as one means of providing electricity within an integrated electricity concession also encompassing mini-grid and/or grid system access. It’s also possible that with standalone system providers increasingly looking to pay-as-you-go arrangements, where they retain ownership of the system until the user has bought it through monthly payments, or even over its full life with the user simply paying for electricity used, regulating electricity supply through standalone systems may become more appropriate.


Price/Tariff Regulation


Prices of standalone systems supplied by the private sector are generally unregulated. Where public funding is used to support provision of standalone systems it may (as with the NAE Case Study of the IDCOL programme in Bangladesh) be appropriate to regulate prices. Also, if the move towards pay-as-you-go, with users paying for electricity as they do from grid or mini-grids, while suppliers retain ownership of the capital equipment, continues or accelerates, regulation of the prices they pay may become more relevant. Regulation of prices for standalone systems, or of electricity supplied through these systems, on an individual basis is impractical given the multiplicity of systems. Uniform price regulation, where a standard price or tariff is set is more likely to be viable. However, any such regulation should recognize the differentials in costs between different types and sizes of standalone system, and parity with grid (or mini-grid) prices should only be attempted if subsidies are available to balance the cost differentials between these different Technologies.


Finance


Though provision of standalone systems requires less capital investment than investment in grid or mini-grid systems, those establishing standalone system business nevertheless require capital for business development and working capital to fund the period (typically three months or more) between purchase/ import of the product by the business and sale to the end-user. Because standalone systems are often imported, this also brings a requirement for access to foreign capital. Where standalone systems are sold to users, it is to these users that much of the requirement for capital investment falls. This need for up-front user finance has formed one of the most substantial barriers to growth of markets for standalone systems (even where these systems are demonstrably an economic option for the user in the longer term). This barrier can be alleviated through micro-finance and similar programmes, and has also driven the growth of pay-as-you-go arrangements whereby the need for up-front finance is transferred to the supplier (though users remain the ultimate source of finance through their payments for electricity).  Though most standalone system providers are private companies, many have struggled to access private finance, reflecting private financiers reluctance to invest in start-up companies without established track-records seeking to grow a new market. Instead many have relied on finance from donors and social funders. This has been one of the main constraints on standalone system market growth.  Public finance, through grants, subsidies and concessionary loans (to both suppliers and users) and tax exemptions (eg VAT and import duty exemptions) have been used to make standalone systems more affordable to users. 


Non-Financial Interventions


Clear national policies and targets and availability of market information have been identified as key factors enabling standalone system providers to assess market scale and so encourage market entry. Regulatory reform, particularly in the finance sector to enable pay-as-you-go arrangements is also seen as vital, as is establishment and enforcement of quality standards to give consumers confidence in products. Exemption from taxes and duties (particularly where this is needed to create a level playing field with other forms of energy access) can catalyse market development, and user awareness raising and development of a workforce with the technical and business skills need to support business growth are also important (and beyond the capacity of individual standalone system businesses) to support its growth.


Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided)


Standalone systems encompass a wide range of technologies from solar lanterns, to solar home systems and pumps, to larger scale diesel, hydro, biomass and wind-powered generators. Because they lack the economies of scale provided by grid (or even mini-grid) systems, the cost per unit of electricity from standalone systems is generally higher than from a grid (or mini-grid) connection. However in areas which are remote from the grid system and are sparsely populated (or lack a substantial energy source), standalone systems may provide the lowest cost option for electricity supply because they avoid the cost of distribution infrastructure. In addition, while the cost per unit of electricity may be relatively high, for low-demand users (eg those only looking for lighting and phone charging) they can still offer the most economic solution. Standalone solutions are also used by those who want back-up for an unreliable grid or mini-grid supply, or who want independence from the grid system.          

In line with the wide range of technologies encompassed by standalone systems, they can be designed to provide any level of electricity. In general, however, the differential in cost between grid/mini-grid and standalone systems increases as the level of supply goes up (particularly for solar standalone systems), and standalone household systems therefore most often provide only Tier 1 (or even lower) access and rarely provide more than Tier 2-3 access, though systems for enterprises and community facilities may be larger and provide a higher level of access (with larger systems often being supported by hydro or fuel rather than solar generation).  


Further Information and Guidance



Relevant Case Studies



►Go to Top


References

Authors

Authors: Mary Willcox, Dean Cooper

Acknowledgements

The Review was prepared by Mary Willcox and Dean Cooper of Practical Action Consulting working with Hadley Taylor, Silvia Cabriolu-Poddu and Christina Stuart of the EU Energy Initiative Partnership Dialogue Facility (EUEIPDF) and Michael Koeberlein and Caspar Priesemann of the Energising Development Programme (EnDev). It is based on a literature review, stakeholder consultations. The categorization framework in the review tool is based on the EUEI/PDF / Practical Action publication "Building Energy Access Markets - A Value Chain Analysis of Key Energy Market Systems".

A wider range of stakeholders were consulted during its preparation and we would particularly like to thank the following for their valuable contributions and insights: - Jeff Felten, AfDB - Marcus Wiemann and other members, ARE - Guilherme Collares Pereira, EdP - David Otieno Ochieng, EUEI-PDF - Silvia Luisa Escudero Santos Ascarza, EUEI-PDF - Nico Peterschmidt, Inensus - John Tkacik, REEEP - Khorommbi Bongwe, South Africa: Department of Energy - Rashid Ali Abdallah, African Union Commission - Nicola Bugatti, ECREEE - Getahun Moges Kifle, Ethiopian Energy Authority - Mario Merchan Andres, EUEI-PDF - Tatjana Walter-Breidenstein, EUEI-PDF - Rebecca Symington, Mlinda Foundation - Marcel Raats, RVO.NL - Nico Tyabji, Sunfunder -



NAE Overview Page

Any feedback would be very welcome. If you have any comments or enquires please contact: mary.willcox@practicalaction.org.ukbenjamin.attigah@euei-pdf.org, or caspar.priesemann@giz.de.

Download the Tool as a Power Point: https://energypedia.info/images/a/aa/National_Approaches_to_Electrification_-_Review_of_Options.pptx


►Go to Top