Difference between revisions of "National Approaches to Electrification – Legal Basis"
***** (***** | *****) m |
***** (***** | *****) m |
||
Line 112: | Line 112: | ||
| | | | ||
*EUEI PDF (2014), Mini-grid Policy Toolkit: Policy and Business Frameworks for Successful Mini-grid Roll-outs <u>[http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_mini-grid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_mini-grid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf]</u> | *EUEI PDF (2014), Mini-grid Policy Toolkit: Policy and Business Frameworks for Successful Mini-grid Roll-outs <u>[http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_mini-grid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf http://www.euei-pdf.org/sites/default/files/field_publication_file/RECP_mini-grid_Policy_Toolkit_1pageview_(pdf,_17.6MB,_EN_0.pdf]</u> | ||
− | * | + | *IRENA (2016), Policies and regulations to support renewable energy mini-grid development through private sector involvement <u><u>[http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_minigrids_2016.pdf http://www.irena.org/DocumentDownloads/Publications/IRENA_Policies_Regulations_mini-grids_2016.pdf]</u></u> |
− | *Senegal. Agence Senegalaise d’Electrification Rurale (2009), Concession d’Electrification Rurale au Senegal, The Africa Electrification Initiative (AEI) Workshop, Maputo, Mozambique 9-12 Juin 2009. <u> | + | *Senegal. Agence Senegalaise d’Electrification Rurale (2009), Concession d’Electrification Rurale au Senegal, The Africa Electrification Initiative (AEI) Workshop, Maputo, Mozambique 9-12 Juin 2009. <u><u>[http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTAFRREGTOPENERGY/Resources/717305-1264695610003/6743444-1268073657582/15.4.Senegal.pdf http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTAFRREGTOPENERGY/Resources/717305-1264695610003/6743444-1268073657582/15.4.Senegal.pdf]</u></u><br/> |
*World Bank, (2000), Regulatory Approaches to Rural Electrification and Renewable Energy: Case Studies from Six Developing Countries <u style="font-size: 13.6px;">[http://www.martinot.info/Martinot_Reiche_WB.pdf http://www.martinot.info/Martinot_Reiche_WB.pdf]</u> | *World Bank, (2000), Regulatory Approaches to Rural Electrification and Renewable Energy: Case Studies from Six Developing Countries <u style="font-size: 13.6px;">[http://www.martinot.info/Martinot_Reiche_WB.pdf http://www.martinot.info/Martinot_Reiche_WB.pdf]</u> | ||
* | * | ||
+ | |||
Senegal. OBA (2007), OBA in Senegal – Designing Technology-Neutral Concessions for Rural Electrification <u>[https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/11034/396090SN0OBApp1140Electric01PUBLIC1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/11034/396090SN0OBApp1140Electric01PUBLIC1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y]</u> | Senegal. OBA (2007), OBA in Senegal – Designing Technology-Neutral Concessions for Rural Electrification <u>[https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/11034/396090SN0OBApp1140Electric01PUBLIC1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/11034/396090SN0OBApp1140Electric01PUBLIC1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y]</u> | ||
Line 128: | Line 129: | ||
| style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(191, 144, 0);" | <br/> | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(191, 144, 0);" | <br/> | ||
| | | | ||
− | *[[ | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems|Bangladesh, IDCOL Solar Home Systems]]<br/> |
*[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/> | *[[NAE Case Study: Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)|Brazil, Luz para Todos (Light for All)]]<br/> | ||
− | *[[ | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Costa Rica, Distribution Cooperatives|Costa Rica, Distribution Cooperatives]]<br/> |
− | *[[ | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Mali, Rural Electrification Programme|Mali, Rural Electrification Programme]]<br/> |
− | *[[ | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems|Peru, Concession Model for Standalone Systems]]<br/> |
− | *[[ | + | *[[NAE Case Study: Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives|Philippines, Islanded Distribution by Cooperatives]]<br/> |
*[[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|South Africa, Integrated National Electrification]]<br/> | *[[NAE Case Study: South Africa, Integrated National Electrification|South Africa, Integrated National Electrification]]<br/> | ||
*[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]<br/> | *[[NAE Case Study: Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology|Tunisia, Low Cost Distribution Technology]]<br/> | ||
Line 142: | Line 143: | ||
<br/> | <br/> | ||
− | = | + | = License = |
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | ||
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 130px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | |
'''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/> | '''<span style="color:#FFFFFF;"><span style="font-size: 13.6px;">Definition:</span></span>'''<br/> | ||
| style="width: 618px;" | | | style="width: 618px;" | | ||
− | '''<span><span></span></span><span><span> | + | '''<span><span></span></span><span><span></span></span><span><span>A non-exclusive permission granted by government (or regulator) to sell electricity or standalone systems. </span></span><span><span></span></span><span><span></span></span>''' |
+ | |||
+ | Licenses are employed to enable regulatory authorities to control who provides electricity or electricity goods, to ensure that they meet quality and safety standards and to allow price controls. At the same time licensing is a means of making clear that electricity providers are entitled to sell – without which private financiers may be reluctant to invest. A license may: | ||
− | + | *Cover the entire country or a specific area or project<br/> | |
+ | *Be time-limited or unlimited<br/> | ||
+ | *Relate to one, several, or all means of electricity provision | ||
|} | |} | ||
Line 162: | Line 167: | ||
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | ||
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <br/> |
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 103, 0);" | | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 103, 0);" | | ||
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Technologies</span><br/> | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Technologies</span><br/> | ||
Line 169: | Line 174: | ||
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | ||
− | + | Grid systems and larger grid-connected mini-grids / distribution systems are usually licensed through a concession arrangement as, often, are larger isolated mini-grids. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (with its non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. (mini-grids below a certain size, are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from licensing). Without a concession, a key question for private mini-grid licensees will be what happens when the main grid arrives, and it may be beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim. Standalone system providers are rarely subject to licensing (beyond general business licensing requirements) though they may be required to meet certain standards in order to access subsidies and tax exemptions. In part this reflects both policy-makers’ and businesses’ perception that as product retailers rather than infrastructure providers or sellers of electricity itself they do not require licensing. Also, without long-term fixed capital investment, private companies have not needed the protection of a concession or license to attract private capital (and would regard it simply as a regulatory burden). With standalone system providers increasingly<br/>looking to pay-as-you-go arrangements, where they retain ownership of the system until the user has bought it through monthly payments, or even over its full life with the user simply paying for electricity used, more formal regulation of standalone system businesses may become more appropriate. | |
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/> |
− | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(49, 101, 153);" | |
− | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"> | + | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Delivery Models</span><br/> |
<br/> | <br/> | ||
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | ||
− | + | Licensing may be regarded as unnecessary with a public delivery model, since one arm of the state is granting a license to another, though it can act as a mechanism for establishing independent and transparent oversight. With private and public-private delivery models, licensing is used to explicitly establish the right for the licensee to sell electricity (or a technology used to provide electricity) as the basis for attracting private participation and protecting users through standards and price controls. | |
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/> |
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" | | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(205, 52, 0);" | | ||
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/> | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Price/Tariff Regulation</span><br/> | ||
Line 189: | Line 194: | ||
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | ||
− | + | One of the purposes of licensing is to provide the vehicle and framework for price/tariff regulation, with license withdrawal being the sanction for failure to comply with price/tariff regulation. Prices may be set on either a uniform or an individual basis. | |
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/> |
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" | | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(32, 56, 100);" | | ||
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><br/> | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Finance</span><br/> | ||
Line 199: | Line 204: | ||
| style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | | style="width: 616px;" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span> | ||
− | + | The right to sell conveyed by a license is the most fundamental requirement for attracting private finance. A licensing regime may also provide a transparent regulatory framework to attract private investment (see below), and may be linked to access to grants, subsidies, tax exemptions and guarantees.<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"></span> | |
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;"></span><br/> |
| style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" | | | style="width: 117px; background-color: rgb(0, 100, 100);" | | ||
<span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/> | <span style="color:#FFFFFF;">Non-Financial Interventions</span><br/> | ||
Line 209: | Line 214: | ||
| style="width: 616px;" | | | style="width: 616px;" | | ||
− | National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the | + | National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the regulatory model employed. Regulatory reform is the path to establishing any licensing framework, including quality and technical standards, and capacity building or technical assistance may be required if the key actors lack the capacity to undertake this regulatory reform. Awareness raising and demand promotion amongst users and service providers, as well as training (capacity building) to develop the skilled workforce needed by licensed electricity businesses can be beneficial alongside financial forms of public support. |
|} | |} | ||
Line 219: | Line 224: | ||
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | ||
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <br/> |
| | | | ||
− | The | + | The key advantage of licensing electricity providers is that it provides the means to impose technical and quality standards and price controls, and thereby protect users, in return for the explicit right to operate. The clarity provided by a well-designed and managed licensing arrangement can serve to attract electricity providers, particularly if long-term capital investment is involved. If licensing is complex, bureaucratic and time-consuming, or imposes disproportionate costs, it may instead delay projects and discourage potential providers, which is the main disadvantage of licensing.<span style="font-size: 13.6px;"></span> |
|} | |} | ||
Line 231: | Line 236: | ||
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | ||
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <br/> |
| style="width: 735px;" | | | style="width: 735px;" | | ||
− | |||
− | |||
− | |||
− | |||
− | |||
− | |||
|} | |} | ||
Line 247: | Line 246: | ||
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | ||
|- | |- | ||
− | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb( | + | | style="width: 10px; background-color: rgb(248, 192, 0);" | <br/> |
| | | | ||
− | + | <br/> | |
|} | |} | ||
Line 255: | Line 254: | ||
<br/> | <br/> | ||
− | = | + | = Unregulated = |
{| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" | {| border="1" cellspacing="1" cellpadding="1" style="width:100%;" |
Revision as of 13:21, 25 June 2018
Legal Basis: The basis on which organisations are legally entitled to sell electricity
Concession
Definition: |
An exclusive right (monopoly) granted by government to sell electricity or standalone systems A concession may:
Concessions are usually granted to attract private investment by guaranteeing the investor protection from competition, or to protect public investment. |
Internactions wiht other NAE Categories:
Technologies
|
Grid systems and larger grid-connected mini-grids / distribution systems and isolated mini-grids almost always require concessions (because of the substantial investment required). As a result, the right to transmit and sell electricity is often reserved to the national grid company and/or mini-grid/distribution system operator (at least within the area they reach). For smaller mini-grids, with lower, shorter-term capital investment, a license (which grants a non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be seen as more appropriate, and mini-grids below a certain size are often unregulated. A key question for private mini-grid investors will be what happens when the main grid arrives? Grid extension into a mini-grid concession area within the concession period may be prohibited, or there may be explicit provision for compensation and transfer of assets to grid ownership. Grid and mini-grid concessions thus often interrelate (with each preventing or having explicit provision for extending into the other’s area). | |
Delivery Models
|
Public delivery models are frequently combined with what are effectively concessions, though the monopoly may be created by, for instance, reserving the right to sell electricity to a national utility company, and may not therefore be labelled as a concession. Oversight and control may then be through organisational hierarchy rather than any explicit regulatory framework. Concessions are used to attract private participation in private and public-private models and may be the means through which public-private models are established. | |
Price/Tariff Regulation
|
Where a concession is granted prices will almost certainly be regulated both to enable private investors to estimate revenues over the concession period and to protect users and ensure that the concessionaire is not over-exploiting their monopoly position. This regulation may be through the terms of the concession itself, rather than through a wider framework. Prices may be set on either a uniform or an individual basis. | |
Finance
|
A concession is a means of attracting private finance, by offering the investor higher levels of sales (in the absence of competition) and lower risk in predicting those sales. It may also be used to protect public investment in infrastructure such as grid systems, and as a means of channelling public financial support into electricity provision. | |
Non-Financial Interventions
|
National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the regulatory model employed. Institutional restructuring (eg of the national utility company) and regulatory reform may be needed to enable concessions to be established and capacity building or technical assistance may be required if the key actors lack the capacity to undertake this regulatory reform or design concession arrangements. Awareness raising and demand promotion amongst users and service providers, as well as training (capacity building) to develop the skilled workforce needed by concessionaires can be beneficial alongside financial forms of public support. |
Advantages and Disadvantages
The key advantage of a concession is that, by removing the potential for others to sell within the concession area, it allows demand to be captured by a single supplier, giving them economies of scale, and makes it easier to forecast volume of sales and so easier for investors to forecast future revenues (whereas license-based price/tariff regulation only reduces price uncertainty). As well as attracting more private finance this may reduce required return on investment and hence finance costs, but it also removes the benefits of competition once the concession has been granted and so places heavier demand on regulation to protect users, though potential providers may be required to compete for the concession through a tender process. Concession approaches can be rigid, and require significant capacity within regulatory authorities to design approaches which attract private finance while avoiding over-exploitation of users. Concessions also, by their nature, create boundaries and so push investors towards project finance and thinking by limiting their ability to expand their business beyond pre-set borders or to continue it beyond the end of a concession period. For capital-intensive infrastructure-based means of electrification (grid and mini-grids), however, a concession may just represent recognition of a natural monopoly and the need for explicit arrangements for arrival of the grid, and it is for these that a concession is most likely to be appropriate. |
Further Informaiton and Guidance
Senegal. OBA (2007), OBA in Senegal – Designing Technology-Neutral Concessions for Rural Electrification https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/11034/396090SN0OBApp1140Electric01PUBLIC1.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y |
Relevante Case Studies:
License
Definition: |
A non-exclusive permission granted by government (or regulator) to sell electricity or standalone systems. Licenses are employed to enable regulatory authorities to control who provides electricity or electricity goods, to ensure that they meet quality and safety standards and to allow price controls. At the same time licensing is a means of making clear that electricity providers are entitled to sell – without which private financiers may be reluctant to invest. A license may:
|
Internactions wiht other NAE Categories:
Technologies
|
Grid systems and larger grid-connected mini-grids / distribution systems are usually licensed through a concession arrangement as, often, are larger isolated mini-grids. For smaller mini-grids, with lower and shorter-term capital investment, a licensing regime (with its non-exclusive right to sell electricity) may be more appropriate, with greater flexibility and a generally less demanding process balancing lack of protection from competition for the investor, while still providing the means to protect users through price/tariff regulation and setting technical and safety standards. (mini-grids below a certain size, are often unregulated, as the administrative burden (and costs) of regulation are seen as disproportionate to the protection it would provide to investors and users, and the right to operate instead being granted through a general derogation from licensing). Without a concession, a key question for private mini-grid licensees will be what happens when the main grid arrives, and it may be beneficial to establish a compensation regime in the event of grid extension, to encourage private mini-grid investment in the interim. Standalone system providers are rarely subject to licensing (beyond general business licensing requirements) though they may be required to meet certain standards in order to access subsidies and tax exemptions. In part this reflects both policy-makers’ and businesses’ perception that as product retailers rather than infrastructure providers or sellers of electricity itself they do not require licensing. Also, without long-term fixed capital investment, private companies have not needed the protection of a concession or license to attract private capital (and would regard it simply as a regulatory burden). With standalone system providers increasingly | |
Delivery Models
|
Licensing may be regarded as unnecessary with a public delivery model, since one arm of the state is granting a license to another, though it can act as a mechanism for establishing independent and transparent oversight. With private and public-private delivery models, licensing is used to explicitly establish the right for the licensee to sell electricity (or a technology used to provide electricity) as the basis for attracting private participation and protecting users through standards and price controls. | |
Price/Tariff Regulation
|
One of the purposes of licensing is to provide the vehicle and framework for price/tariff regulation, with license withdrawal being the sanction for failure to comply with price/tariff regulation. Prices may be set on either a uniform or an individual basis. | |
Finance
|
The right to sell conveyed by a license is the most fundamental requirement for attracting private finance. A licensing regime may also provide a transparent regulatory framework to attract private investment (see below), and may be linked to access to grants, subsidies, tax exemptions and guarantees. | |
Non-Financial Interventions
|
National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the regulatory model employed. Regulatory reform is the path to establishing any licensing framework, including quality and technical standards, and capacity building or technical assistance may be required if the key actors lack the capacity to undertake this regulatory reform. Awareness raising and demand promotion amongst users and service providers, as well as training (capacity building) to develop the skilled workforce needed by licensed electricity businesses can be beneficial alongside financial forms of public support. |
Advantages and Disadvantages
The key advantage of licensing electricity providers is that it provides the means to impose technical and quality standards and price controls, and thereby protect users, in return for the explicit right to operate. The clarity provided by a well-designed and managed licensing arrangement can serve to attract electricity providers, particularly if long-term capital investment is involved. If licensing is complex, bureaucratic and time-consuming, or imposes disproportionate costs, it may instead delay projects and discourage potential providers, which is the main disadvantage of licensing. |
Further Informaiton and Guidance
Relevante Case Studies:
|
Unregulated
Definition: |
Delivery of electricity access by an entity which is part publically and part privately owned or by a mix of publically and privately owned entities or using a combination of public and private finance This includes cases where:
|
Internactions wiht other NAE Categories:
Technologies
|
Public-private models for grid systems might include:
For grid connected mini-grids and distribution systems:
For isolated mini-grids:
Use of public finance (grants, subsidies and loans) to enhance affordability and support market growth often results in a public-private model for standalone systems, even when there is a purely private-sector chain of manufacturers, importers, distributors and retailers. There could also be benefits in some circumstances from government energy agencies becoming directly involved in the standalone system market, by forming a joint entity to supply systems or by taking on one of the roles along the value chain (eg providing a distribution service for all system providers), as a means of supporting market development. | |
Legual Basis
|
Because a public-private model involves private ownership and investment, an explicit legal framework will be required for any form of electrification which involves significant long-term capital investment in order to attract private finance and allow for price regulation to protect users. A concession, which offers protection from competition, will provide the greatest attraction for private financiers. Where no long-term capital investment is involved, as with standalone systems sold directly to users, no legal control (beyond that for any business) may be necessary – however if there is partial public sector ownership, a transparent legal framework may be required to convince private market participants that they are not facing unfair competition, and also to ensure that any public finance is not being misused. | |
Price/Tariff Regulation
|
Where significant capital investment is involved, a transparent framework for price/tariff regulation is likely to be required to attract the private element into any public-private partnership. Tariff regulation will also protect users and provide a means of ensuring that public finance is not being misused or exploited by the private sector. It may also demonstrate to private market participants that they are not facing unfair competition from partially publically-owned market participants. | |
Finance
|
All public-private partnerships will involve a combination of private and public finance. Private finance will come through ownership and investment in, and loans to electricity providers. Public finance may come through these routes, but may also be through various forms of grant, subsidy, tax exemption or guarantee. Ultimately public-private models, like other forms of electricity provision, will rely on connection and ongoing charges, and standalone system purchases from users. For multi-user systems (grids and mini-grids) there is also likely to be some element of cross-subsidy between users. | |
Non-Financial Interventions
|
National energy planning is key to establishing the optimum mix of technologies to meet electrification needs across the country, regardless of the delivery model employed. Institutional restructuring may be needed to establish public-private partnerships and capacity building or technical assistance may be required if the key actors lack the capacity to undertake regulatory reform or design arrangements for public financial support. Awareness raising amongst users and other potential market actors and service providers, as well as training (capacity building) to develop the skilled workforce needed by new energy access businesses can be beneficial alongside financial forms of public support. Public-private partnership may also provide the means to bring in new technology, with the private sector providing the technology know-how while the public sector bears the risk inherent in new technology which private investors may be reluctant to take on. |
Advantages and Disadvantages (Including Level of Electricity Provided)
Public-Private partnerships offer the potential to combine the benefits of both models, with public security being combined with private efficiency, innovation and flexibility. Bringing in private finance can extend the capacity for electricity provision beyond that which the public sector alone can offer, while public financial support can be used to attract private finance and make electricity affordable for users. Combining public and private inputs is not, however, simple. Significant expertise is required to ensure that private investment is attracted while making optimum use of public resources. Moreover the appropriate form of public-private partnership will change as markets develop and levels of electricity access increase – and this must be recognised while at the same time creating regimes which can give the private sector the confidence in the future they require to invest. |
Further Informaiton and Guidance
|
Relevante Case Studies:
References
Authors
Authors: Mary Willcox, Dean Cooper
Acknowledgements
The Review was prepared by Mary Willcox and Dean Cooper of Practical Action Consulting working with Hadley Taylor, Silvia Cabriolu-Poddu and Christina Stuart of the EU Energy Initiative Partnership Dialogue Facility (EUEIPDF) and Michael Koeberlein and Caspar Priesemann of the Energising Development Programme (EnDev). It is based on a literature review, stakeholder consultations. The categorization framework in the review tool is based on the EUEI/PDF / Practical Action publication "Building Energy Access Markets - A Value Chain Analysis of Key Energy Market Systems".
A wider range of stakeholders were consulted during its preparation and we would particularly like to thank the following for their valuable contributions and insights: - Jeff Felten, AfDB - Marcus Wiemann and other members, ARE - Guilherme Collares Pereira, EdP - David Otieno Ochieng, EUEI-PDF - Silvia Luisa Escudero Santos Ascarza, EUEI-PDF - Nico Peterschmidt, Inensus - John Tkacik, REEEP - Khorommbi Bongwe, South Africa: Department of Energy - Rashid Ali Abdallah, African Union Commission - Nicola Bugatti, ECREEE - Getahun Moges Kifle, Ethiopian Energy Authority - Mario Merchan Andres, EUEI-PDF - Tatjana Walter-Breidenstein, EUEI-PDF - Rebecca Symington, Mlinda Foundation - Marcel Raats, RVO.NL - Nico Tyabji, Sunfunder -
Any feedback would be very welcome. If you have any comments or enquires please contact: mary.willcox@practicalaction.org.uk, benjamin.attigah@euei-pdf.org, or caspar.priesemann@giz.de.
Download the Tool as a Power Point: https://energypedia.info/images/a/aa/National_Approaches_to_Electrification_-_Review_of_Options.pptx